El viejo Almacén. BsAs

Surplus Approach

“Es necesario volver a la economía política de los Fisiócratas, Smith, Ricardo y Marx. Y uno debe proceder en dos direcciones: i) purgar la teoría de todas las dificultades e incongruencias que los economistas clásicos (y Marx) no fueron capaces de superar, y, ii) seguir y desarrollar la relevante y verdadera teoría económica como se vino desarrollando desde “Petty, Cantillón, los Fisiócratas, Smith, Ricardo, Marx”. Este natural y consistente flujo de ideas ha sido repentinamente interrumpido y enterrado debajo de todo, invadido, sumergido y arrasado con la fuerza de una ola marina de economía marginal. Debe ser rescatada."
Luigi Pasinetti


ISSN 1853-0419

Entrada destacada

Teorías del valor y la distribución una comparacion entre clásicos y neoclásicos

Fabio PETRI   Esta obra, traducida por UNM Editora, ha sido originalmente editada en Italia con el título: “Teorie del valore e del...

Mostrando entradas con la etiqueta Italian economists. Mostrar todas las entradas
Mostrando entradas con la etiqueta Italian economists. Mostrar todas las entradas

18 feb 2015

Institucionalismo y Teoría Economica: del "neoclasicismo" a la Teoría Clásica


Por Enrico Sergio Levrero*



Tomado de la Revista de Economía Institucional, número 31, volumen 16, segundo semestre de 2014, pp.81-99
En este trabajo el autor examina el núcleo clásico y marginalista de la teoría economica, mostrando sus diferencias y el porqué el esquema del excedente permite incorporar aspectos sociales e institucionales para explicar la economía. Tambien se analiza las dificultades del institucionalismo norteamericano en incorporar esta teoria, y ascribir a la posicion marginalista, dando un mayor soporte a su difusion.


1-Una de las críticas al institucionalismo y la razón para que fuera empujado a los márgenes de la teoría económica es que no propuso un sistema teórico viable para determinar el valor y la distribución que
triunfara sobre el paradigma neoclásico. Esta debilidad fue evidente, por ejemplo, en el cambio progresivo de la economía laboral desde institucionalistas estadounidenses como E1y, Commons y Hoxie al "neoclasicismo" de Stig1er, Becker y Mincer. También fue evidente en la derrota de la escuela histórica alemana en el Methodenstreit por Menger y los economistas austriacos.

Si la falta de una estructura analítica y de una teoría del valor alternativa a la neo clásica debilitó a la escuela histórica alemana y al viejo institucionalismo 1 , esa estructura analítica hoy podría ser proporcionada por la teoría clásica, cuyo origen se remonta a la escuela histórica escocesa de Hume, Hutchinson y Ferguson, y cuyos problemas en la determinación de los precios relativos y la tasa de ganancia fueron resueltos por Producción de mercancías por medio de mercancías de Sraffa. El método de los clásicos -caracterizado por la combinación del razonamiento deductivo e inductivo- es semejante al de Marx: a la teoría del valor se le atribuye una tarea más estrecha que en la teoría neoclásica, mientras que en los datos que determinan los precios -métodos de producción, tasa de salarios y producto (social- influye un conjunto de circunstancias económicas, históricas y sociales que se analizan en otra etapa del análisis.

Este artículo busca explicar por qué el institucionalismo no se convirtió en el punto de referencia en teoría económica, y mostrar que la teoría clásica puede incorporar muchas de sus contribuciones, a diferencia de la teoría neoclásica. Presenta un ejemplo de esta capacidad y del papel esencial de los factores sociales e institucionales en la teoría de Smith y Ricardo con respecto al mercado de trabajo.

2-LA DERROTA DEL VIEJO INSTITUCIONALISMO
Dos casos de la historia del institucionalismo pueden ayudar a aclarar por qué fue empujado a los márgenes de la teoría económica.
Uno se refiere a la economía laboral; el otro a los debates sobre el método entre economistas neoclásicos como Menger, Fisher y Knight, por una parte, y la escuela histórica alemana y el institucionalismo estadounidense, por la otra. Considerando el primer caso, Spencer observa con razón que los institucionalistas no "propusieron un sistema teórico viable"y que los neoclásicos "triunfaron en el debate porque sí 10 proporcionaron" (2009,109). Pudieron entonces "ignorar a los economistas laborales institucionalistas porque solo hacían una crítica negativa y no ofrecían una teoría alternativa". Y de institucionalistas estadounidenses como Ely, Commons y Hoxie -que fundaron la economía laboral (McNulty, 1980; Boyer y Smith, 2001)- se pasó así a la segunda generación de economistas laborales (Dunlop, Kerr, Lester, Reynolds), que empezaron a utilizar herramientas de la teoría neoclásica (aunque aún subrayando el papel esencial de los factores sociales e históricos en el mercado de trabajo), para dar el paso definitivo al neoclasicismo, con las obras de Stigler, Becker y Mincer.

Las consecuencias de este cambio son claras. Por ejemplo, al subsumir totalmente el análisis del trabajo en el aparato técnico de la economía neoclásica, la teoría del capital humano de Becker (1964) y Mincer (1974) despojó al concepto de trabajo de su contenido social, histórico e institucional. Eso mismo se puede decir de la apertura de la caja negra de la información imperfecta y asimétrica en el mercado laboral desde la década de 1970 (Alchian y Demsetz, 1972; Williamson, 1975; Akerlof y Yellen, 1986). En la literatura que subraya esas asimetrías, las fuerzas de la oferta y la demanda siempre están presentes, aunque congeladas por hipótesis ad hoc, mientras que se olvida la importancia de las necesidades humanas y de los aspectos sociales y culturales del sitio de trabajo. Además, ignora las dificultades relacionadas con una medida unívoca del esfuerzo y con la determinación de una relación definida entre este último y la tasa de salarios, y la motivación del trabajo se reduce a la evasión y el oportunismo. Igual que en la doctrina mercantilista (ver, p. ej., Mun, 1664), se considera que el trabajador es perezoso y que solo se debe elegir entre usar el garrote o la zanahoria para incentivarlo a trabajar.

3. Pero, de nuevo, ¿qué explica el paso a la teoría neoclásica? Si consideramos la experiencia estadounidense, ¿qué favoreció el predominio marginalista después de un periodo de fuerte presencia institucionalista en las universidades y en el debate científico, pese al sentimiento general de que en el corto plazo desaparecería cualquer teoría del valor basada en el cálculo hedonista (Parry, 1921a, 128)?
La respuesta no se encuentra en el creciente formalismo de la economía (B1aug,2003), pues neo clásicos como Marshall y Menger eran conscientes de sus peligros 2, y este fue en gran medida consecuencia de la evolución de la teoría marginalista después de la división que siguió a la publicación de Valory capital de Hicks3• Tampoco se encuentra en el predominio, en el momento de dar ese paso (o, mejor, de su epílogo
final), de la posición metodológica de Milton Friedman (1953), para quien el realismo de los supuestos no es importante en el desarrollo de la teoría económica. Igual que en el caso de la economía laboral, parece encontrarse en la falta de una teoría del valor alternativa a la neoclásica.

Este punto se puede entender revisando la experiencia de la escuela histórica alemana y del Methodenstreit en el que triunfaron Menger (1883-1884) y los economistas austriacos. Cuando se revisa ese debate queda claro dónde estaba la debilidad del institucionalismo: el énfasis correcto de Roscher y Hildebrand en la existencia de leyes económicas históricas relativas -así como el énfasis correcto de Schmoller y la joven escuela histórica alemana en la necesidad de investigaciones empíricas para clasificar los fenómenos económicos y derivar leyes económicas- fue criticado fácilmente por Menger (y después de él por Bohm- Bawerk, 1890; Robbins, 1984; y Schumpeter, 1982) apelando a la necesidad del razonamiento analítico y la abstracción" para dar a la economía un marco teórico que ayudara a analizar las tendencias
de los sistemas económicos.

De hecho, la crítica de Menger a la escuela histórica alemana no estaba exenta de ambigüedades y contradicciones, y en gran medida no se puede concordar con ella. Menger sostenía que solo se debía pasar de unidades y elementos únicos a leyes más complejas, y que los axiomas económicos surgen de hechos de la experiencia que no son verificables empíricamente. Al mismo tiempo, propuso una visión dinámica y evolutiva del funcionamiento de los sistemas económicos que dio origen a la noción austriaca de competencia (Kirzner, 1973); una noción que no es fácil reconciliar con el concepto neo clásico de equilibrio basado en las fuerzas de la demanda y la oferta, con su énfasis en el tiempo lógico, en cambios "falsos" y reversib1es, en intercambios que solo ocurren a los valores de equilibrio, etc.
Sin embargo, el punto es que ningún enfoque de la economía puede evitar la necesidad, subrayada por Menger, de una teoría coherente del valor para analizar la dinámica de las economías capitalistas. Lo que no entendió la escuela histórica alemana es que sin esa teoría no es posible explicar el funcionamiento de un sistema de mercados y su evolución. El ataque de Schmoller a Menger no se debería haber concentrado en la necesidad de investigaciones históricas y análisis inductivos, sino en el tipo de teoría que propuso Menger, de acuerdo con la cual serían suficientes algunas premisas evidentes (Barkai, 1996) para explicar la acción económica como asignación de recursos escasos entre usos alternativos para maximizar la utilidad.



Ver todo el trabajo ACA

*Profesor asociado, Facultad de Economía, Universidad de Roma III
[enricosergio.levrero@uniroma3.it]. Este ensayo es una reelaboracion de la
conferencia pronunciada en la First Summer School of the European Association
of Evolutionary Politic al Economy. Traducción de Alberto Supelano. Fecha de
recepción: 4 de junio de 2013, fecha de modificación: 2 de mayo de 2014, fecha
de aceptación: 29 de octubre de 2014. Sugerencia de citación: Levrero, E. S.
"Institucionalismo y teoría económica: del 'neoclasicismo' a la teoría clásica",
Revista de Economía Institucional 16, 31, 2014, pp. 81-99.

1 Aquí no nos referimos al nuevo institucionalismo de Williamson, Posner
y Olson, que -siguiendo a Hayek y a Menger (1871 y 1892)- interpreta la
evolución institucional como resultado de comunicaciones e interacciones de
agentes racionales individuales en forma no planeada. Sobre las limitaciones de
esta visión, ver Hodgson (1988), quien subraya que en "el estado de naturaleza"
también debían existir reglas y normas sociales para que hubiera interacciones entre
agentes, y que muchas instituciones son el resultado de conflictos entre grupos
sociales, porque protegen los intereses de la clase dirigente. Sobre este aspecto,
ver North (1990), quien señala que se pueden crear y mantener instituciones
"ineficientes" si favorecen a algún grupo social.

2 Como se sabe, Bohrrr-Bawerk, Marshall, Menger y von Wieser no consideraban
las matemáticas como herramienta de investigación sino como representación del
discurso económico. Fisher, Walras y Wicksell, y más tarde Debreu y Koopmans
adoptaron una posición diferente.
3 Aquí no me refiero al razonamiento deductivo en sí mismo, el cual es necesario
en toda teoría, ni al uso de las matemáticas cuando es apropiado, sino
al proceso de a..xiomatización y formalización que ha vaciado progresivamente
los conceptos económicos de su contenido empírico, desviando la atención a la
consistencia lógica, argumentando que en economía, a diferencia de lo que ocurre
en las ciencias naturales, no hay una base empírica o experimental suficiente
para extraer principios científicos (ver Debreu, 1986 y 1991). Esto ha llevado
a abandonar la idea de Keynes de que en economía necesitamos un sistema de
pensamiento y no una estructura axiomática, y de que "buena parte de la teorización
económica se ve perjudicada porque trata de aplicar métodos matemáticos
muy precisos a un material que es en sí mismo demasiado vago para soportar
ese tratamiento" (Keynes, 1973, XIV, 379). Sobre el formalismo en economía, ver
también Backhouse (1998).

4 El punto en cuestión debería haber sido la necesidad de una teoría del valor,
pues la vieja escuela histórica alemana no negó la necesidad de la abstracción,
como aparece implícita, por ejemplo, en la teoría de las etapas de desarrollo
propuesta por List o Hildebrand. Pero la falta de una teoría del precio alternativa
la debilitó. Ver más adelante.

15 jun 2010

Letter from the Italian Economists

Nos llega una carta firmada por Economistas Italianos sobre las desastrosas medidas de contracción de la demanda impulsadas por Alemania. Ver sobre el tema


To the kind attention of the European colleagues
(In order to organize a European network, please contact us: info@letteradeglieconomisti.it)

A RESTRICTIVE POLICY WORSENS THE CRISIS,
ADDS FUEL TO SPECULATION AND CAN BRING TO THE
DISINTEGRATION OF THE EURO ZONE. THE DIRECTION OF
ECONOMIC POLICY NEEDS TO BE CHANGED TO PREVENT
ANOTHER BREAKDOWN OF INCOMES AND EMPLOYMENT


To the Members of Italian Government and Parliament
To the Italian representatives in the European Union Institutions
To the representatives of the political parties and the trade unions
To the Italian representatives in the European Union Institutions and the ESCB
To the President of the Republic


The extremely serious global economic crisis, and the related crisis in the euro zone, will not be solved either by cutting wages, pensions, social services, education, research, culture and essential public services, or by directly or indirectly increasing taxes on employment and on the weaker social classes.

In fact, there is the grave danger that the introduction in Italy and Europe of so-called “austerity” measures will further accentuate the features of the crisis, making insolvency, business failure and unemployment grow faster, and in all likelihood forcing some member states at some point to withdraw from European monetary union.

The fundamental point that must be understood is that the current instability of the monetary Union is not merely the result of slick accounting or easy spending. It is actually the outcome of a far deeper interweaving between the global financial crisis and a series of imbalances in the euro zone, deriving mainly from the unsustainable economic liberalist nature of the Treaty of Union and from the restrictive economic policy of the member states which systematically show a surplus in their balance of payments.

≈≈≈

The world crisis that exploded in 2007-2008 is still underway. Since no intervention was made on its structural causes, we have never actually emerged from it. As has been acknowledged from many quarters, one of the main explanations for this crisis is the The world crisis that exploded in 2007-2008 is still underway. Since no intervention was made on its structural causes, we have never actually emerged from it. As has been acknowledged from many quarters, one of the main explanations for this crisis is the For many years this gap was compensated by an exceptional escalation in financial speculation and in private debt, which, starting from the United States, acted as a stimulus for global demand.

Today there are some who are counting on a return to world growth based on a new financial boom in the United States. By unloading a huge quantity of unrecoverable private debts on the state balance sheets, it is hoped to give a new boost to finance and to the related mechanism of accumulation. We believe that a credible world recovery on this basis is highly unlikely. In any case, it would be tenuous and short-lived. At the same time we find it illusory to hope that without a profound reform of the international monetary system China would be willing to give up its commercial profits and act as the driving force for world demand.

In short, we are facing the dramatic situation of a world economic system that lacks a primary source of demand that, is, a “sponge” that can absorb the production.

The unsolved global crisis has been particularly felt in the European monetary Union. The evident vulnerability of the euro zone derives from profound internal structural imbalances, whose main cause lies in the economic liberalist design of the Maastricht Treaty, in the expectation that the various areas of the Union can be rebalanced purely through market mechanisms, and in the restrictive deflationary economic policy of countries with a systematic balance of payments surplus. Particularly important among these is Germany, which for some time has been oriented towards keeping wages down compared to productivity, demand and imports, and towards the penetration of foreign markets in order to increase German firms’ share of the European market. With such policies the ‘surplus’ countries do not contribute to the development of the euro area but paradoxically are pulled ahead by the weaker countries. More specifically, Germany accumulates a considerable surplus in its balance of trade, while Greece, Portugal, Spain and even France tend to get into debt. Even Italy, despite the very low growth of its national income, finds itself buying more from Germany than it sells, thus accumulating growing debts.

The complete mobility of capital in the euro zone has hugely favoured the creation of credit-debit imbalances between countries. For a long time, relying on the idea of the efficiency of the market, it was believed that rising debt ratios between member states should be considered the postive sign of greater financial integration in the euro zone. But today it is quite clear that the supposed efficiency of the financial markets finds no confirmation in practice and the imbalances accumulated prove to be unsustainable.

It is for these reasons that operators on the financial markets are betting on the disintegration of the euro zone. They foresee that owing to the continuation of the crisis the revenue of the member states will decline and the earnings of a great many businesses and banks will be further reduced. In this way it will be increasingly difficult to guarantee the repayment of debts, both public and private. Various countries could therefore be progressively pushed out of the euro zone, or they themselves might decide to leave in order to escape from the deflationary spiral. The risk of generalised insolvency and of debts being reconverted into the national currency is therefore the real issue motivating the speculators. So the turbulence of the financial markets rests on a series of real contradictions. However, it is equally true that the speculators’ expectations add fuel to the lack of confidence and therefore tend to be fulfilled. In fact, bearish operations on the markets push up the difference between interest rates and income growth rates, and can mean that debtors who were previously able to repay their debts are suddenly made insolvent. Financial operators, who often act in conditions that are non-competitive and anything but symmetrical in terms of information and market power, are therefore able not only to foresee the future but also to help determine it, following a pattern that has nothing to do with the so-called “fundamentals” of orthodox economic theory and the presumed criteria of efficiency described in its basic versions.

≈≈≈

In such a scenario we think it is pointless trying to oppose speculation with mere loan agreements in exchange for support for restrictive policies on the part of the indebted countries. The loans will in fact simply postpone the problems without solving them. And policies of “austerity” lower the demand even more, bringing wages down and therefore further lessening the ability to repay loans on the part of debtors, both public and private. Though significant, the change in monetary policy by the ECB, which says it is ready to buy government bonds on the secondary market, is given a new perspective by the announcement that the central bank wants to “sterilise” these operations with manoeuvres on currencies or within the banking system which would have the opposite effect.

The errors committed are undoubtedly due to the recessive remedies of economic liberalism suggested by economists tied to the schemes of analysis in vogue in past years, but that do not seem capable in the slightest of grasping the salient aspects of the workings of the economic system.

It is quite clear that the stubbornness with which such depressive policies are pursued is not simply the result of misunderstandings generated by economic models whose logical coherence and empirical relevance has now been strongly challenged within the academic community itself.

The fondness for so-called “austerity” is actually the expression of consolidated social interests. There are in fact some people who see the current crisis as a chance to accelerate the processes of dismantling social services, fragmenting employment and restructuring and centralising European capital. The underlying idea is that the capital that emerges victorious from the crisis will be able to trigger rapid accumulation, moreover exploiting the lower competitivity on the markets and a further weakening of employment.

It must however be understood that if such interests are backed up, not only is one acting against the workers’s interests, but the conditions are also being created for an uncontrolled centralisation of capital, the productive desertification of Southern Italy and of whole macroregions in Europe, migratory processes that are increasingly hard to control, and ultimately for gigantic debt-driven deflation, comparable only to that of the Thirties.

≈≈≈

The Italian government has so far put in place a policy designed to foster this dangerous deflationary spiral. And the further budget belt-tightening announced, together with the persistent tendency to reduce the defence of employment, can only cause further cuts to income, after the plunge already recorded in Italy in 2009. Keep it clearly in mind that the scientific assumptions underlying the belief that such policies can improve the economic situation and the balance sheet and therefore safeguard the country from an attack of speculation are highly questionable. Instead, in taking this road there is the risk of aggravating the crisis, multiplying insolvencies and therefore speculation.

Nor can the opposition forces be said to have so far put forward a clear programme of alternative economic policy. Greater awareness is spreading about the seriousness of the crisis and the mistakes of the past, but voices have been raised from some sectors of the opposition suggesting contradictory or second-rate stances, like the proposals designed to introduce further short-term work contracts or to carry out the massive privatization of public services. Even the frequent calls for so-called “structural reforms” are counterproductive, when instead of being characterised by measures designed to oppose waste and the privilege of the few, they are translated into further proposals for the downsizing of social and employment rights.

As a warning for the future, it is best to remember that in 1992 Italy was subjected to a speculative attack similar to those currently underway in Europe. At the time, the Italian workers accepted an irksome programme of “austerity”, based above all on the compression of the cost of labour and social security spending. At the time, like today, it was said that the sacrifices were necessary to defend the lira and the national economy from speculation. However, shortly after the programme was passed, shares in the national currency suffered fresh attacks. In the end Italy left the European Monetary System anyway, and the lira was sharply devalued. Workers and much of the community therefore paid twice: because of the policy of “austerity” and because of the increase in the cost of imported goods.

It should also be remembered that, with the prevailing justification of lowering public debt in relation to GDP, in past years our country has carried out a massive programme of privatisations. Now, the programme’s effects on public debt, which were slight anyway, have largely vanished in the wake of the crisis, and the implications in terms of the country’s positioning in the international division of employment, economic growth and social well-being are today considered highly questionable by the most reputable scientific literature.

≈≈≈

We therefore believe that the approach adopted up to now needs to be abandoned before it is too late.

It must be taken into account that for a long time it is likely that there will not be a driving force that can ensure a strong stable recovery for business and for world development. To prevent the crisis from getting worse and to avoid the collapse of the project of a unified Europe, what is needed therefore is a new vision and a change in the general directions of economic policy. In other words, Europe must take an independent path to develop its forces of production, increase its well-being, safeguard the environment and the region, and guarantee social equity.

First of all, for a debate of such importance to mature in the various countries involved and in the political institutions, space must be given to the democratic process. In other words, there must be time available. That is why as a preliminary step, we propose the immediate introduction of a check on speculation. To this end, initiatives at a national but also at a coordinated European level are underway, but the measures being introduced still seem weak and inadequate. Putting an end to speculation is undoubtedly possible, but uncertainty and political ambiguity need to be got rid of. The ECB must therefore commit itself fully to buying the stocks under attack, and stop “sterilising” its interventions. Adequate taxes need to be imposed designed to discourage short term financial transactions, along with effective administrative controls on the movement of capital. If the conditions for taking concerted action were not found, it would be far better to intervene at once on a national level, with the methods available, than to delay acting or to do nothing at all. It is only through such initiatives that decisions can be taken in the time required by democratic institutions, without the latter being subjected to the constant threat of a speculative attack.

The experience of the past teaches us that to effectively counteract deflation a wage floor needs to be imposed, through minimum wages, constraints on firing and new general rules to protect employment and unionising processes. Above all at the present stage, the idea of entrusting the process of destruction and creation of jobs to market forces alone is analytically senseless, as well as politically irresponsible.

In coordination with monetary policy, we need to encourage the countries with a balance of payments surplus, especially Germany, to take appropriate measures to expand the demand so as to trigger a process of virtuous rebalancing of European Monentary Union member states’ balance of payments. The leading ‘surplus’ countries have a great responsibility, on this point. The rescue or the destruction of the Union will depend largely on their decisions.

We need a system of progressive taxation coordinated at a European level, which can help to reverse the trend towards income disparity that contributed to the outbreak of the crisis. We need a shift of the fiscal load from employment to capital profits and to rents, from incomes to wealth, from PAYE taxpayers to tax evaders, from the poor areas of the Union to the rich ones.

There should be a significant expansion of the Union’s federal budget and the possibility of issuing European bonds. There should be the attempt to coordinate fiscal policy and European monetary policy for the purpose of drawing up a development plan designed to achieve full employment and the regional rebalancing not only of buying power but also of the productive capacities in Europe. The plan should follow a different logic from the often inefficient and aid-oriented mentality that governed the European development funds. It should be based first of all on the public production of collective goods ranging from the funding of state research facilities to fight the monopoly on intellectual property, to the safeguarding of the environment, to regional planning, to sustainable labour mobility, to the care of individuals. These are goods that inevitably generate market failures and are not understood by the limited logic of the private capitalistic firm, but at the same time are indispensable in strengthening the forces of production and in guaranteeing equity and social and civil progress.

We need to regulate and restrict the access of small savers and pension funds to the financial market. We need to restore the principle of separation between banks offering ordinary short-term credit, and finance companies that work on the medium to long term.

To counter any strategies of dumping and of “exporting the recession” by non-EMU countries, we should consider a system of conditional opening of markets, of capital and goods. This opening can be complete only if coordinated wage and development policies are put in place.

≈≈≈

We are well aware of the distance existing between our recommendations and the current fearful decline in the state of European economic policy.

We believe however that the present direction of economic policy may soon prove to be unsustainable. If the conditions do not exist for the realisation of a development plan based on the objectives outlined, there will be an extemely high risk of debt-driven deflation and the consequent disintegration of the euro zone. This is because some countries could be sucked into a vicious spiral, caused by short-sighted national “austerity” policies and the resulting pressure of speculation. At a certain point these countries could be forced out of the monetary union or could deliberately decide to leave it in order to try to create their own economic policies in defence of internal markets, incomes and employment. If things actually went in that direction, it is obvious they would not necessarily be seen as the main culprits for the crisis of the European union.

Such eventualities make us think that the conditions no longer exist for reviving the European spirit by appealing only to our shared ideals. The truth is that what is underway is the most violent and determined attack on Europe as a political player and on the last bastions of social security in Europe. Now more than ever, then, in order to survive and be revitalised, Europeanism needs to embody a meaning and real opportunities for coordinated economic, social and civil development.

Essentially what is needed is to start a broad and open debate on the reasons and responsibilities for the dire mistakes being made in economic policy, on the consequent risks of a worsening of the crisis and of a disintegration of the euro zone, on the urgent need for a change in the direction of European economic policy.

If the hoped for change in European economic policy should not eventuate, unemployment will increase and the crisis of the euro zone will worsen. In this case, national authorities could be forced to take autonomous economic policy decisions in order to sustain internal markets, incomes and employment.

SIGNATURES

Nicola Acocella (Università di Roma ‘La Sapienza’), Roberto Artoni (Università Bocconi), Aldo Barba (Università di Napoli ‘Federico II’), Enrico Bellino (Università Cattolica di Milano), Sergio Beraldo (Università di Napoli ‘Federico II’), Paola Bertolini (Università di Modena e Reggio Emilia), Mario Biagioli (Università di Parma), Salvatore Biasco (Università di Roma ‘La Sapienza’), Adriano Birolo (Università di Padova), Giovanni Bonifati (Università di Modena e Reggio Emilia), Bruno Bosco (Università di Milano Bicocca), Paolo Bosi (Università di Modena e Reggio Emilia), Emiliano Brancaccio (Università del Sannio), Katia Caldari (Università di Padova), Rosaria Rita Canale (Università Parthenope di Napoli), Francesco Carlucci (Università di Roma ‘La Sapienza’), Maurizio Caserta (Università di Catania), Lucilla Castellucci (Università di Roma ‘La Sapienza’), Duccio Cavalieri (Università di Firenze), Sergio Cesaratto (Università di Siena), Laura Chies (Università di Trieste), Guglielmo Chiodi (Università di Roma ‘La Sapienza’), Roberto Ciccone (Università Roma Tre), Giorgio Colacchio (Università del Salento), Lilia Costabile (Università di Napoli ‘Federico II’), Francesco Crespi (Università Roma Tre), Carlo Devillanova (Università Bocconi), Carmela D’Apice (Università Roma Tre), Marcello De Cecco (Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa), Pasquale De Muro (Università Roma Tre), Elina De Simone (Università Orientale di Napoli), Giancarlo De Vivo (Università di Napoli ‘Federico II’), Davide Di Laurea (ISTAT), Amedeo Di Maio (Università Orientale di Napoli), Antonio Di Majo (Università Roma Tre), Fernando Di Nicola (ISAE), Giuseppe Di Vita (Università di Catania), Leonardo Ditta (Università di Perugia), Sebastiano Fadda (Università Roma Tre), Riccardo Faucci (Università di Pisa), Alberto Feduzi (Università Roma Tre), Stefano Figuera (Università di Catania), Massimo Florio (Università di Milano), Giuseppe Fontana (Università del Sannio), Guglielmo Forges Davanzati (Università del Salento), Saverio Fratini (Università Roma Tre), Lia Fubini (Università di Torino), Stefania Gabriele (ISAE), Pierangelo Garegnani (Università Roma Tre), Andrea Ginzburg (Università di Modena e Reggio Emilia), Enrico Giovannetti (Università di Modena e Reggio Emilia), Claudio Gnesutta (Università di Roma ‘La Sapienza’), Augusto Graziani (Università di Roma ‘La Sapienza’), Andrea Imperia (Università di Roma ‘La Sapienza’), Bruno Jossa (Università di Napoli ‘Federico II’), Paolo Leon (Università Roma Tre), Sergio Levrero (Università Roma Tre), Paolo Liberati (Università Roma Tre), Stefano Lucarelli (Università di Bergamo), Giorgio Lunghini (Università di Pavia), Vincenzo Maffeo (Università di Roma ‘La Sapienza’), Ugo Marani (Università di Napoli ‘Federico II’), Maria Cristina Marcuzzo (Università di Roma ‘La Sapienza’), Ferruccio Marzano (Università di Roma ‘La Sapienza’), Fabio Masini (Università Roma Tre), Giovanni Mazzetti (Università della Calabria), Luca Michelini (Università LUM), Salvatore Monni (Università Roma Tre), Mario Morroni (Università di Pisa), Marco Musella (Università di Napoli ‘Federico II’), Oreste Napolitano (Università di Napoli ‘Parthenope’), Sebastiano Nerozzi (Università Cattolica di Milano), Mario Nuti (Università di Roma ‘La Sapienza’), Guido Ortona (Università del Piemonte Orientale), Ugo Pagano (Università di Siena), Daniela Palma (ENEA), Antonella Palumbo (Università Roma Tre), Sergio Parrinello (Università di Roma ‘La Sapienza’), Marco Passarella (Università di Bergamo), Rosario Patalano (Università di Napoli ‘Federico II’), Stefano Perri (Università di Macerata), Cosimo Perrotta (Università del Salento), Fabio Petri (Università di Siena), Antonella Picchio (Università di Modena e Reggio Emilia), Marco Piccioni (Università di Napoli ‘Federico II’), Federico Pirro (Università di Bari), Massimo Pivetti (Università di Roma ‘La Sapienza’), Felice Roberto Pizzuti (Università di Roma ‘La Sapienza’), Elena Podrecca (Università di Trieste), Paolo Ramazzotti (Università di Macerata), Fabio Ravagnani (Università di Roma ‘La Sapienza’), Riccardo Realfonzo (Università del Sannio), Angelo Reati (ISEG), Sergio Rossi (Università di Friburgo), Francesco Scacciati (Università di Torino), Giovanni Scarano (Università Roma Tre), Roberto Schiattarella (Università di Camerino), Ernesto Screpanti (Università di Siena), Annamaria Simonazzi (Università di Roma 'La Sapienza'), Riccardo Soliani (Università di Genova), Luca Spinesi (Università di Macerata), Antonella Stirati (Università Roma Tre), Francesca Stroffolini (Università di Napoli ‘Federico II’), Stefano Sylos Labini (ENEA), Valeria Termini (Università Roma Tre), Mario Tiberi (Università di Roma ‘La Sapienza’), Guido Tortorella Esposito (Università del Sannio), Paolo Trabucchi (Università Roma Tre), Attilio Trezzini (Università Roma Tre), Pasquale Tridico (Università Roma Tre), Domenica Tropeano (Università di Macerata), Vittorio Valli (Università di Torino), Michelangelo Vasta (Università di Siena), Alessandro Vercelli (Università di Siena), Carmen Vita (Università del Sannio), Adelino Zanini (Politecnica delle Marche), Gennaro Zezza (Università di Cassino).


Promoters of the initiative: Bruno Bosco (Università di Milano Bicocca), Emiliano Brancaccio (Università del Sannio), Roberto Ciccone (Università Roma Tre), Riccardo Realfonzo (Università del Sannio), Antonella Stirati (Università Roma Tre).
Contacts: info@letteradeglieconomisti.it

http://www.letteradeglieconomisti.it/english.htm